×

or

Cartel Penalty and Leniency under the Competition Act, 2002

Cartel Penalty and Leniency under the Competition Act, 2002

In markets characterized by faircompetition, firms attract consumers only when they keep the prices lower than their competitors, constantly innovate to improve quality and reduce costs, use their resources in the most efficient manner and take decisions which are not only economically wise but better than the competitors. Therefore, faircompetition increases efficiency and leads to a greater good. On the other hand, competition may be harsh for less efficient firms because they would not be able to keep pace with more-efficient firms and would ultimately perish. To evade the rigours of competition, firms may collude with each other to earn super normal profits by increasing prices, creating artificial scarcity, dividing market amongst them, that adversely affect consumers, chill incentives to innovate, maintain status-quo and create artificial entry barriers. Thus, the effects of collusion could be cascading. It is for these reasons that cartels are considered to be the supreme-evil of antitrust across jurisdictions and attract the heaviest penalties, and in a number of jurisdictions attract criminal sanctions.

Under the Competition Act, 2002 (“Act”), proviso to Section 27 (b) provides discretion to the Competition Commission of India (“CCI”) to prescribe a penalty of up to three times of profit upon the participating firm for each year of the continuance of the cartel or ten percent of the participating firm’s turnover for each year of the continuance of the cartel, whichever is higher. The CCI has been using its discretion with an iron-hand by imposing maximum penalty possible in the cases of cartel.

Firms that indulge in cartel conduct generally do not leave any direct evidence of collusion and usually hatch such conspiracies in secrecy. At times, coordination amongst cartel members are orchestrated through common agents or entities that do not even operate at the same level of the market. Whether cartel is orchestrated directly or indirectly, gaining access to incriminating evidence that may stand the test of judicial scrutiny is invariably a challenging task. Parallel conduct by companies, standing alone, does not meet the requirement of ‘agreement’ amongst the parties charged with the offence of cartel. Further, in the absence of evidence, it is very often difficult to discard the defence that their parallel conduct is truly independent or unilateral.

The Director General (“DG”), which is the investigating authority of the CCI, has been given very wide powers to conduct investigation under the Act and enjoys discretion to summon any person, take evidence on oath, keep documents under his custody, conduct dawn-raids, etc. Further, non-compliance of any directions of the DG may entail a fine which may extend to rupees one lakh for each day during which such failure continues, subject to a maximum of rupees one crore. Notwithstanding such wide powers, the CCI has not been very successful in prosecuting cartels, except the bid rigging cases where records of identical pricing that cannot be explained by any rational conduct is made available by the public authorities inviting such bids.

The CCI has initiated a number of investigations into cartel conduct based on customer complaints, press reports, reports from state agencies, etc. However, it’s endeavours to successfully prosecute cartels have met with a limited success. In this regard, the experience from international jurisdictions suggest that the most frequent way to burst and prosecute cartels has been the Leniency Programs, which have proved to be an effective tool for anti-cartel enforcement. In general, the Leniency Program affords full or partial immunity from penalties or prosecution to a corporation or individual when certain requirements are met.

Section 46 of the Act provides power to the CCI to impose lesser penalties or no penalty upon an enterprise which has made a true, vital and full disclosure of information in respect to a cartel. Such disclosures, referred to as ‘leniency applications’ in competition law parlance, allows the CCI, on the one hand, to get crucial insider evidence and direct evidence and, on the other, protects the leniency applicant by insulating it from potentially debilitating penalties. Further, leniency applicants may also get saved from dawn raids and other forms of intrusive investigation. Thus, leniency provisions provide a win-win situation to both.

Pertinently, a firm may be inclined to file a leniency application only when the benefits of filing a leniency application would outweigh the benefits of not filing it. Scholars have opined that three essential conditions must exist for making leniency successful2: a) Sanctions to a cartel should be severe, b) there shall be a perception of a high risk of detection, and c) anti-cartel enforcement and leniency policies should be transparent and predictable. Accordingly, it is important that both ‘carrot and stick’ is applied judiciously – by making punishments severe and debilitating on the one hand and incentivizing recourse to leniency on the other, to make anti-cartel enforcement programme effective. At this stage, it may be pertinent to examine the application of the carrot and stick policy by the CCI.

As regards the policy of stick, it may be pertinent to state that Section 27 (b) provides for imposition of penalties which could be as high as three times the profit or 10% of the turnover for every year of the cartel. However, the approach taken by the CCI has been inconsistent while penalizing the members of a cartel. For e.g., in the case of cartelization by public sector insurance companies3, the CCI imposed a penalty of 2% of the average of the turnover because the CCI considered the importance of insurers’ solvency for the consumers as a mitigating factor and the penalty was further reduced to1% by the COMPAT in appeal. Similarly, in the recent case of Director Supplies vs. Shree Cement & Ors.4, the CCI inflicted a penalty of 0.3% upon the cement manufacturers for indulging in bid-rigging. As per the CCI, since the collusion had a likelihood of causing an appreciable adverse effect on competition but no actual adverse effect was shown, hence a lesser penalty was inflicted. Therefore, no clear cut guidelines emerge from the decisional practices of the CCI on the quantum of penalties.

THE FIRST LENIENCY DECISION

As regards the policy of carrot, the CCI has very recently passed only one leniency order in the matter of Cartelization in respect of tenders floated by Indian Railways for supply of Brushless DC Fans and other electrical items. It is heartening that a good beginning has been made. Further, since it is public knowledge that there are few more leniency cases being looked in to by the CCI, the coming months may provide more certainty about the outcomes in such cases.

This aforesaid leniency case was taken up by the CCI suo moto, based on the information received from the Superintendent of Police, Anti-Corruption HQ, Central Bureau of Investigation (CBI), New Delhi stating that during an inquiry into certain alleged misconduct by a public servant (Shri Sandeep Goyal) they had found that three firms i.e., M/s Pyramid Electronics, Parwanoo (‘Opposite Party No 1’), M/s R Kanwar Electricals, Noida (‘Opposite Party No 2’) and M/s Western Electric and Trading Company, Delhi (‘Opposite Party No 3’) (collectively referred to as ‘OPs’) had cartelised in respect of the tenders floated by the Indian Railways and the Bharat Earth Movers Limited (‘BEML’) for the supply of Brushless DC fans (‘BLDC fans’) and other electrical items. The CBI had found an email of OP-1 which contained all the information regarding details of four tenders of Indian Railways and BEML for procurement of BLDC fans. It contained the quantity unit value, rates to be quoted by OPs and quantities to be shared amongst them in these four tenders which was the same quoted by the railway tender. Finding s ‘prima facie’ case of anticompetitive agreement, the CCI directed the DG to conduct an investigation. During the course of investigation, OP 1 filed an application under Section 46 of the Act, read with Competition Commission of India (Lesser Penalty) Regulations, 2009 with the CCI requesting for lesser penalty. It not only cooperated with the investigating officer but, pertinently, also waived confidentiality on its identity as well as the information furnished. Based on the investigation Report of the DG, the CCI observed that OP 1, OP 2 and OP 3 had decided to divide the four tenders amongst themselves in a mutually agreed manner, and devised an arrangement of bid rotation. Accordingly, the CCI imposed a penalty of ₹ 62, 36,634 on OP 1, ₹ 20, 01,012 on OP 2 and ₹ 2, 09, 14,961 on OP 3. Further, since the CCI decided to grant 75% reduction on penalty to OP-1 under section 46 of the Act, the amount of Penalty was reduced to ₹ 15,59,159/-. Additionally, under Section 48 of the Act, CCI also imposed a penalty on the key persons responsible for such cartelisation at the rate of 10 percent of the average of their income for the last three preceding FY amounting to ₹ 46,594 on OP 1, which after a 75% reduction was reduced to ₹ 11,648/, ₹ 84,837 on OP 2 and ₹ 2, 13,919 on OP 3, respectively.

It thus appears that the CCI has sufficiently incentivized and brought in clarity for the potential leniency applicants by this decision. It has been argued by few that a 100% reduction in the fine should have been given in the aforesaid matter since the evidence given by the applicant was crucial and that the party, because of waiver of its confidentiality, may face potential risks of compensation claims and other damages. We are, however, of the view that reduction in penalty by 75% is a judicious balance arrived at by the CCI; the CCI order clearly states that if the party had made the disclosure before the commencement of the DG’s investigation, it would have enjoyed greater reduction in penalties. In this regard, it is pertinent to note that the evidence provided by the CBI, (i.e. an email communicating the rates to be quoted by the parties to the tender) was clinching enough to establish an agreement amongst the parties all by itself. Therefore, the CCI has in fact adopted a rather easy threshold to grant leniency. Such an approach by the CCI is welcome and ought to be appreciated by the stake-holders as creating an amicable environment for the parties to file leniency applications would go a long way in its anti-cartel enforcement activity.

WAY FORWARD

While a good beginning has been made, more needs to be done. As of now, it is not clear as to what kind of disclosure / information shall be considered as “full” and “vital”, as it is the basic requirement for grant of leniency. Moreover, the use of the words ‘may’ in Section 46, creates an impression that the CCI may not grant leniency even if the applicant has made “full” and “vital” disclosure as per its knowledge. Thus, it seems important that the words “full” and “vital” are properly explained and the circumstances under which the CCI would not grant leniency may be clearly stated. Such circumstances may include where the firm has used the leniency application only as a strategic move, waiting for the right time to confess, in light of the cartel not being profitable any longer or where it has been the ring leader of the cartel or threatened other participants from disclosing the existence of the cartel, or as may be considered appropriate by the CCI. While the Regulations5 stipulate a number of factors which the CCI shall give due regard while exercising discretion, such as, ‘the stage at which the applicant comes forward with the disclosure, the evidence already in possession of the CCI, the quality of the information provided by the applicant, and the entire facts and circumstances of the case, they may not generate sufficient certainty and could even be vague in as much as an applicant may file leniency application believing that the information being submitted by it is crucial but the CCI may not consider so and therefore refuse to grant leniency.

Another issue of great relevance seems to be the status of confidentiality, as it may be crucial for the protection of a party from pecuniary and other damages on account of claims from affected parties. While it is certain that CCI would grant confidentiality, it is uncertain whether the same would continue even at the appellate stage and this uncertainty adversely affects the Leniency programme.

There is also a lack of clarity as to whether the leniency provisions would apply in cases where the cartel conduct, amongst the entities operating at the same level of the market, has been facilitated by such entities who operate in a different market, such as vertical / adjacent or a totally different market. Further, such conduct facilitating or orchestrating cartels could also be present in ‘hub and spoke cartels’. Both in the United States and the European Union, entities who do not operate at the same level of the market but facilitate cartel conduct amongst enterprises operating at one level of the market have been found guilty and penalised.6 Accordingly, it may be helpful for the CCI to state whether such facilitators and co-conspirators would be eligible for leniency so as to assist in dealing with cartels.

To create a race for the door to leniency, companies that secretly colluded to fix prices or rig bids should also be charged for committing fraud on taxpayers and the government exchequer by falsely creating the appearance of competition. Since the CCI does not have power to bring criminal charges, other law enforcement agencies (like the CBI, the economic offences wing of the police, etc.) could be impressed upon to bring in criminal charges against the cartelists under the various provisions of the Indian Penal Code, wherein the leniency applicants could be given the benefit of an approver. Further, by treating cartelisation and bid rigging as misdemeanours under the provisions of the Companies Act, 2013, the Registrar of Companies could cancel the Director Identification Numbers (“DIN”) of officials, who did not apply for leniency, for a certain period of time making it difficult for them to run the affairs of any company. As the provisions of the Competition Act are in addition to, and not in derogation of, the provisions of any other law for the time being in force, such a course of action may be legally sustainable and need to be tested.

Thus, a multi-pronged action plan against firms and individuals engaged in cartel conduct could prove to be the real “stick” in cartel enforcement, making the leniency provisions more attractive and effective.

About Author

Subodh Deo

Subodh Prasad Deo, Partner and Head of Competition Law Practice, Saikrishna & Associates, (Former Additional Director General, Competition Commission of India) E: [email protected] [email protected] M: +91-9910737966

Tanveer Verma

Tanveer Verma, Associate, Saikrishna & Associate